欢迎来到淘文阁 - 分享文档赚钱的网站! | 帮助中心 好文档才是您的得力助手!
淘文阁 - 分享文档赚钱的网站
全部分类
  • 研究报告>
  • 管理文献>
  • 标准材料>
  • 技术资料>
  • 教育专区>
  • 应用文书>
  • 生活休闲>
  • 考试试题>
  • pptx模板>
  • 工商注册>
  • 期刊短文>
  • 图片设计>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换

    Agricultural markets in developing countries.pdf

    • 资源ID:34292638       资源大小:34.01KB        全文页数:12页
    • 资源格式: PDF        下载积分:15金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    会员登录下载
    微信登录下载
    三方登录下载: 微信开放平台登录   QQ登录  
    二维码
    微信扫一扫登录
    下载资源需要15金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
    验证码:   换一换

     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
    5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

    Agricultural markets in developing countries.pdf

    1 Agricultural markets in developing countries Christopher B. Barrett and Emelly Mutambatsere Cornell University Final version, June 2005 Entry in Lawrence E. Blume and Steven N. Durlauf, editors, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition (London: Palgrave Macmillan, forthcoming). 2ID: A000209 Abstract The history of agricultural markets in developing countries reflects attempts to establish the appropriate government responses to the inefficiencies created by incomplete institutional and physical infrastructure and imperfect competition. Government intervention in the 1960s and 1970s to resolve market failures gave way in the 1980s to market-oriented liberalization to get prices right and, more recently, to get institutions right. But markets openness may accentuate the latent dualism of a modern, efficient marketing sector, accessible only to those with adequate scale and capital, alongside a traditional, inefficient marketing channel to which the poor are effectively restricted. Agricultural markets in developing countries Markets aggregate demand and supply across actors at different spatial and temporal scales. Well-functioning markets ensure that macro and sectoral policies change the incentives and constraints faced by micro-level decision makers. Macro policy commonly becomes ineffective without market transmission of the signals sent by central governments. Similarly, well-functioning markets underpin important opportunities at the micro level for welfare improvements that aggregate into sustainable macro-level growth. For example, without good access to distant markets that can absorb excess local supply, the adoption of more productive agricultural technologies typically leads to a drop in farm-gate product prices, erasing all or many of the gains to producers from technological change and thereby dampening incentives for farmers to adopt new technologies that can stimulate economic growth. Markets also play a fundamental role in managing risk associated with demand and supply shocks by facilitating adjustment in net export flows across space and in storage over time, thereby reducing the price variability faced by consumers and producers. Markets thus perform multiple valuable functions: distribution of inputs (such as fertilizer, seed) and outputs (such as crops, animal products) across 3space and time, transformation of raw commodities into value-added products, and transmission of information and risk. Per the first welfare theorem, competitive market equilibria help ensure an efficient allocation of resources so as to maximize aggregate welfare. The micro-level realities of agricultural markets in much of the developing world, however, include poor communications and transport infrastructure, limited rule of law, and restricted access to commercial finance, all of which make markets function much less effectively than textbook models typically assume. A long-standing empirical literature documents considerable commodity price variability across space and seasons in developing countries, with various empirical tests of market integration suggesting significant and puzzling forgone arbitrage opportunities, significant entry and mobility barriers, and highly personalized exchange (Barrett, 1997; Platteau, 2000; Fackler and Goodwin, 2001; Fafchamps, 2004). Widespread inefficiencies result from incomplete or unclear property rights, imperfect contract monitoring and enforcement, high transactions costs, and binding liquidity constraints. Such failures often motivate government intervention in markets, although interventions have often done more harm than good, either by distorting incentives or by creating public sector market power. The history of agricultural markets in developing countries reflects evolving thinking on the appropriate role for government in trying to address the inefficiencies created by incomplete institutional and physical infrastructure and imperfect competition. The emphasis in the 1960s and 1970s on government intervention to resolve market failures gave way in the 1980s to market-oriented liberalization to get prices right and, more recently, to a focus on getting institutions right. Past approaches Agricultural marketing of most major export and food commodities and of modern inputs such as fertilizer, machinery and hybrid seed was historically highly regulated by developing country governments into the 1980s, via input price controls and subsidies, oligopolistic input markets, monopsonistic produce marketing boards, pan-seasonal and pan-territorial administrative commodity pricing, oligopolistic processing industries, and fixed wholesale and retail prices. Commodity prices were generally set below market 4levels, implicitly taxing producers while subsidizing consumers. Marketing channels were typically very inefficient, with centralized storage and processing facilities and government-imposed grades and standards for product quality, although these were not always and everywhere enforced. Sometimes these inefficient systems provided satisfactory coordination of marketing channels, but that was by no means universal. Heavy government presence, especially pan-seasonal and pan-territorial producer pricing, and fixed retail pricing systems and bans on private commerce effectively eliminated most incentives for private arbitrage or investment in fixed capital by marketing intermediaries. Meanwhile, management by government fiat too often facilitated corruption, which often had a devastating long-run impact on economic governance. In addition to state-run marketing boards, producer marketing cooperatives were prevalent in developing countries at all levels of the marketing chain, ranging from credit unions through farmer cooperatives to wholesale-level cooperatives. Credit unions commonly accumulated funds for input purchase or served as intermediaries for government-subsidized credit programmes. Farmer marketing cooperatives typically facilitated bulk input procurement, price negotiation, and sharing of transportation costs. Wholesale cooperatives mainly assembled bulk commodity lots for sale into government processing and distribution channels. Cooperatives have often worked well in specialized production areas distant from major markets, and with homogenous production of not-so-perishable commodities such as coffee. However, due to high administrative and coordination costs, free-rider problems and political interference, cooperative systems have not lived up to expectations in most developing countries, and many have collapsed. In contrast to the major export and domestic staple food crops, smaller-scale food commodities for domestic consumption, such as indigenous fruits and vegetables, have almost always operated on a free market basis, with little history of state intervention or price regulation. These markets are characterized by many cash, spot market transfers of product between intermediaries en route from producer to consumer, many small, non-specialized and unorganized buyers and sellers, few if any grades or standards, one-on-one (dyadic) price negotiations, poor market information systems, and mostly informal contracts, largely enforced through social networks (Fafchamps, 2004). Such marketing channels depend disproportionately on rural periodic markets prevalent in most of the 5developing world, arguably the closest one ever gets to a true free market: free of government regulation, subsidies and taxes, and lacking public goods such as physical infrastructure, contract law, public market price information systems, or codified product grades and standards. Indeed, they have been termed the flea market economy by Fafchamps and Minten (2001). The emerging problems of state agricultural market control Given the inherent variability of agricultural production and the significance of agriculture in economic activity and general well-being in developing countries, price stabilization policies were long considered necessary for economic stability. However, a number of problems emerged. First, the fixing of commodity prices below market levels inevitably created a disincentive for agricultural producers. By the late 1970s, low producer prices had led to the stagnation of production and exports and to increased parallel market activity, including cross-border smuggling, in many developing countries, especially in those areas of Africa and Central America that were largely bypassed by the Green Revolution. The second major problem was the fiscal and political sustainability of government agricultural market interventions. The inefficiencies of parastatal marketing boards, along with the repression of private market intermediation, led to unreliable supplies of consumer goods for politically important urban populations. Moreover, those inefficiencies, combined with the numerous subsidies and frequent corruption within government-controlled marketing channels, became too costly for central governments, which faced massive pressure from international donors in the 1980s and 1990s to trim expenditures and to eliminate price controls (Timmer, 1986). Economic liberalization: market relaxation and state compression Market-oriented agricultural policy reforms were a centrepiece of economic liberalization in developing countries in the 1980s and 1990s, commonly within the context of broader structural adjustment programmes designed to restore fiscal and current account balance, to reduce or eliminate price distortions, and to facilitate efficient price transmission so as to stimulate investment and production. The new focus was on re-establishing a close 6correspondence between local and world market prices, so-called border parity pricing. The withdrawal of the state from agricultural market intermediation, specifically price discovery, was seen as a necessary condition in getting prices right, itself a necessary condition for improving market efficiency and stimulating investment and productivity growth (Timmer, 1986). The market-oriented reforms typically implemented by developing country governments included, on the input side, the liberalization of land and labour markets, decontrol and de-licensing of input production, supply and distribution, removal of input subsidies and price controls, closure of loss-making credit schemes, liberalization of credit markets, and reform of agricultural extension. On the output markets side, reforms included commodity price liberalization, the removal of parastatal monopoly power and commodity movement restrictions, and reduction in tariffs and quotas on imports. The net result of these reforms typically turned on the balance between the pro-competitive effects of reduced government interference in marketing operations what Lipton (1993) termed market relaxation and the anti-competitive effects of reduction of public goods and services that underpin private market transactions what Lipton (1993) termed state compression. Since the two phenomena were typically inextricable in agricultural liberalization initiatives, experiences varied markedly. The empirical evidence suggests that commodity prices generally increased after market reforms, often stimulating an increase in production, especially of export crops. These price increases also facilitated the emergence of supermarket chains, export-oriented outgrower schemes and export processing zones, and a generalized stimulus to agro-industrialization in developing countries (Reardon and Barrett, 2000; Sahn, Dorosh and Younger, 1997). Increased investment in the downstream marketing channel has transformed the orientation of many agricultural markets from raw commodity towards processed product markets, and with this increased investment came increased competition. In countries such as Chile, India and South Africa, private firms now play a leading role in development of improved seed varieties, producing and distributing inputs, post-harvest processing and modern retailing through supermarkets and restaurant chains (Reardon et al., 2003; Reardon and Timmer, 2005). Both formal and informal 7traders entered agricultural commodity marketing channels as government controls fell away, from rural periodic markets all the way through urban retail markets. However, market entry has tended to be limited to certain marketing niches not protected by capital, information or relationship barriers, with substantial bottlenecks in other areas such as inter-seasonal storage and motorized transportation. Neither widespread entry into market intermediation activities nor workably competitive markets emerged everywhere, let alone quickly. For example, because long-haul motorized transportation in rural markets tends to involve considerable sunk costs and some economies of scale due to poor road conditions and high vehicle maintenance costs, entry into this sector of the markets has often been limited after the removal of legal and policy barriers to entry (Barrett, 1997). Meanwhile, the end of pan-seasonal and pan-territorial administrative pricing has brought increased price risk, with consequences for investment incentives facing both producers and market intermediaries (Barrett and Carter, 1999). The elimination of input subsidies and removal of government monopsony power in crop marketing has also often led to reduced access to input financing and increased input prices. The withdrawal of parastatals from core input marketing activities created a void that the private sector often failed to fill due to underdeveloped physical communications, power and transport infrastructure, credit constraints and continued bureaucratic impediments that increased transactions costs for input suppliers. In addition, periodic state and donor-funded input programmes have often reduced profitability and frustrated private investments. Input credit schemes by processors have been used in the post-reform period in an attempt to overcome the low input use resulting from these access problems, for example in the cotton sectors of Mali and Uganda and horticultural export sectors of Kenya and Zimbabwe. Although the level of reform implementation differed from country to country, in many cases reform was only partially implemented and policy reversals were common (Jayne and Jones, 1997, Kherallah et al., 2002). In important food and export markets, liberalization efforts have been prolonged and incomplete, reflecting the difficulty in relinquishing government control in the face of uncertainty and political pressures to intervene in order to resolve perceived inequities or inefficiencies in market performance. For example, parastatals remain active in the West African cotton sector, the southern 8African maize sector has not been fully liberalized, and in Indonesia BULOG continues to operate amid private marketing companies. The ebb and flow of market-oriented reforms and the frequency with which governments have engaged

    注意事项

    本文(Agricultural markets in developing countries.pdf)为本站会员(e****s)主动上传,淘文阁 - 分享文档赚钱的网站仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知淘文阁 - 分享文档赚钱的网站(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

    温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。




    关于淘文阁 - 版权申诉 - 用户使用规则 - 积分规则 - 联系我们

    本站为文档C TO C交易模式,本站只提供存储空间、用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。本站仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知淘文阁网,我们立即给予删除!客服QQ:136780468 微信:18945177775 电话:18904686070

    工信部备案号:黑ICP备15003705号 © 2020-2023 www.taowenge.com 淘文阁 

    收起
    展开