Incorporating Observed and Unobserved.docx
《Incorporating Observed and Unobserved.docx》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《Incorporating Observed and Unobserved.docx(11页珍藏版)》请在淘文阁 - 分享文档赚钱的网站上搜索。
1、Copyright 2000. All rights reserved. Incorporating Observed and Unobserved Heterogeneity in Urban Work Travel Mode Choice Modeling CHANDRA R. BHAT Department of Civil Engineering, University of Texas at Austin, Austin, Texas An individuals intrinsic mode preference and responsiveness to level-of-ser
2、vice variables affects her or his travel mode choice for a trip. The mode preference and responsiveness will, in general, vary across individuals based on observed (to an analyst) and unobserved (to an analyst) individual characteristics. The current paper formulates a multinomial logit-based model
3、of travel mode choice that accommodates variations in mode preferences and responsiveness to level-of-service due to both observed and unobserved individual characteristics. The model parameters are estimated using a maximum simulated log-likelihood approach. The model is applied to examine urban wo
4、rk travel mode choice in a multiday sample of workers from the San Francisco Bay area. Most work travel mode choice models are based on the random utility maximization framework of microeconomic theory. The random utility maximi- zation framework assumes that an individuals choice of mode on any cho
5、ice occasion is a reflection of underlying indirect utilities associated with each of the available modes and that the individual se- lects the alternative that provides her or him the highest utility (or least disutility). The indirect util- ity that an individual associates with each mode is not o
6、bserved to the demand analyst, who then as- sumes that this utility is composed of three compo- nents: a) an intrinsic individual-specific mode bias term that varies across individuals and that repre- sents the bias of the individual toward the mode due to observed and unobserved (to the analyst) in
7、divid- ual factors (such as sex, lifestyle, and culture); b) the utility that the individual derives from observable (to an analyst) level-of-service characteristics of- fered by the mode for the individuals trip; and c) a mean-zero random term that captures the effect of unobserved modal characteri
8、stics or unknown mea- surement error in modal level-of-service attributes (more generally, this final third term represents the effects of all omitted variables that are not individ- ual specific). Ideally, we should obtain individual- specific parameters for the first two utility compo- nents; that
9、 is, for the intrinsic mode biases and for 228 the subjective evaluations of modal level-of-service attributes. However, the data used for mode choice estimation are usually cross-sectional or comprise very few observations on each individual. This pre- cludes estimation at the individual level and
10、con- strains the modeler to pool the data across individ- uals. In such pooled estimations, the analyst should, in some way, accommodate taste differences (i.e., heterogeneity in intrinsic mode biases and hetero- geneity in responsiveness to level-of-service at- tributes) across individuals. In part
11、icular, if the as- sumption of taste homogeneity is imposed when there is taste heterogeneity, the result is inconsis- tent model parameter estimates and even more se- vere inconsistent choice probability estimates (see CHAMBERLAIN, 1980; the reader is also referred to HSIAO, 1986 and DIGGLE, LIANG,
12、 and ZEGER, 1994 for a detailed discussion of heterogeneity bias in discrete-choice models). Taste heterogeneity may be incorporated in travel mode choice models by introducing observed individ- ual socio-economic characteristics as alternative- specific variables and by interacting level-of-service
13、 variables with observed individual characteristics (such as using a travel cost over income specifica- tion or using a market segmentation scheme). How- ever, it is very likely that taste heterogeneity will remain even after accounting for differences in ob- Transportation Science, 2000 INFORMS 004
14、1-1655 / 00 / 3402-0228 $05.00 Vol. 34, No. 2, May 2000 pp. 228 238, 1526-5447 electronic ISSN Copyright 2000. All rights reserved. q q q q qk HETEROGENEITY IN TRAVEL MODE CHOICE / 229 served individual characteristics (see FISCHER and NAGIN, 1981). This taste heterogeneity due to unob- served indiv
15、idual attributes is generally ignored in travel mode choice modeling. In this paper, we formulate a multinomial logit- based model of work travel mode choice that accom- modates taste heterogeneity due to both observed and unobserved individual attributes. The formula- tion ensures the correct sign
16、on the level-of-service parameters (for example, a negative coefficient on the time and cost variables) for all individuals. The model takes the form of a random-coefficients logit (or RCL) structure. The RCL structure has been known for a long time, but there have been few applications of this stru
17、cture. The primary reason is that the choice probabilities in the RCL structure do not have a closed-form expression and generally in- volve high dimensional integration. However, in the past few years, the advent of simulation techniques to approximate integrals has facilitated the applica- tion of
18、 the RCL structure (see BHAT, 1998; BROWN- STONE and TRAIN, 1997; and TRAIN, 1998). The mode choice model in this paper is estimated from repeated work travel mode choices of workers The utility Uqit that an individual q associates with an alternative i on choice occasion t may be written in the fol
19、lowing form: Uqit qxqit qit (1) where xqit is a vector of observed variables (includ- ing alternative specific constants), q is a corre- sponding coefficient vector that may vary over indi- viduals but does not vary across alternatives or time, and qit is an unobserved extreme value ran- dom term th
20、at captures the idiosyncratic effect of all omitted variables that are not individual specific. qit is assumed to be identically and independently distributed across all choice occasions and indepen- dent of q and xqit. A number of different specifications may be used for the coefficient vector q in
21、 Eq. 1. To facilitate the following discussion, we partition the coefficient vec- tor q: q asc , ls , (2) q q where asc is the coefficient sub-vector on the alter- obtained from a multi-day travel survey conducted in the San Francisco Bay area. It is important to note that repeated mode choice data
22、from workers is needed to accommodate unobserved variations in native specific constants and ls is the coefficient sub-vector on the level-of-service variables. One pos- sible specification is then to write each element of the asc as a deterministic function of an observed asc asc intrinsic mode bia
23、ses across individuals. In conven- tional cross-sectional work mode choice models that use a single observation for each individual, it is impossible to separate the effect of unobserved het- erogeneity in intrinsic bias from the effect of omitted variables that are generic to all choice occasions (
24、see BHAT, 1998 for an application that allows variation in level-of-service responsiveness, but is unable to accommodate unobserved heterogeneity in intrinsic mode preferences because it uses cross-sectional data). The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The vector zq of individual character
- 配套讲稿:
如PPT文件的首页显示word图标,表示该PPT已包含配套word讲稿。双击word图标可打开word文档。
- 特殊限制:
部分文档作品中含有的国旗、国徽等图片,仅作为作品整体效果示例展示,禁止商用。设计者仅对作品中独创性部分享有著作权。
- 关 键 词:
- Incorporating Observed and Unobserved
限制150内